Distance to the Lake: How to
Price Amenities?
Stephen Chung
Managing Director
Zeppelin Real Estate Analysis Limited
November 2005
Many
friends and clients view their own properties better, and thus of higher
value, than those owned by others, especially when they deem their
properties offer certain convenience or amenities which the
others do not. Such amenities could be easy access to subway stations,
parks, good school districts and so on, and such amenities do sometimes
bring in relatively better prices.
This
reminded your humble author of his days in grad school when a professor used
the example of a frog and its distance to the lake. It went like
this. Frogs need to be near water (ponds, lakes etc) for food and survival
and they can only be so many feet away (maximum distance) from the water
edge beyond which they may endanger their own well-being. Thus, if a frog is
like a human and has money, it will tend to pay top price for a home right
next to the lake (assuming it is not afraid of flood etc), a less than top
but still good price for halfway through the maximum distance, and a lower
(lowest) price for being at the maximum distance. Beyond this, rationally
the frog will not pay anything because it cannot even survive there
(theoretically it may even receive money for willing to risk its life living
there).
The above
is not difficult to comprehend. What is slightly more complicated is the ¡¥price
curve¡¦ i.e. the changes in the price level as the distance to the
lake increases (or decreases depending on which direction one is going).
While there could be numerous combinations for the curve, the following
represent some of the basic ones:
A)
A straight
line down (and without residual value) inversely proportional to the
distance
= let us
say the maximum distance to the lake that a frog can tolerate and survive is
100 meters (or around 328 feet = we are no biologists so do not take this
seriously). Let us also assume the frog has $100 to spend and that the
livable distance closest to the lake starts from the 1 meter mark. In this
scenario, and for neatness, the frog is willing to spend $100 at 1 meter
mark, $51 for the 50 meter mark, and $1 for the 100 meter mark.
¡@
B)
Slower
price decreases initially but quicker pace of decreases as the distance to
the lake increases
= using the same assumptions, in the scenario the frog may still be willing
to pay $80 even for the 80 meter mark i.e. only $20 (20% of money) was
deducted despite having traveled 80 meters (80% of maximum distance) but
then the remaining 20 meters (20% of maximum distance) will see a total drop
of $80 (80% of money).
C)
Faster
price decreases initially but slower pace of price decreases as the distance
to the lake increases
= again
using the same assumptions, in the scenario the frog behaves just the
opposite to (B) above. The first 20 meters may already see some $80 being
taken off, while the rest of the distance (80 meters) will witness only a
total of $20 downward price change.
D)
Hybrid
= a combination of the above and the possibilities are many. For instance,
it may drop slow initially up to the 30 meter mark, become a straight
depreciation between the 31 and 70 meter marks, and then drop fast from the
71 meter mark.
Naturally,
the above scenarios are very simple and actual ones could be more complex.
As to which curves would match what amenities, this requires
comprehensive research and market observation. For instance, many
residential projects highlight their proximity to public transportation
systems or shopping malls, with one theme being ¡§convenience¡¨ i.e. one can
walk there in comfort without the need to take a cab or bus. Thus, the
walking effort required, especially in terms of ¡¥time¡¦, assuming the walk is
reasonably pleasant (e.g. under cover and protected from weather elements),
could be crucial. Yet this time requirement may differ from person to
person, generation to generation, society to society, and so on. People in
the 1960s would consider a 15-minute walk to be reasonable, yet people today
may deem no more than 5 minutes to be acceptable. Hence speculatively,
residences that offer 5-minute or less walks to subway stations, shopping
malls etc may indeed attract more buyers and higher prices than similar
residences nearby, yet this ¡¥premium¡¦ can drastically decrease or even be
eliminated once beyond the 5-minute walk distance (or perception thereof).
In
addition, not only is this amenity ¡§premium¡¨ different to different home
buyers, its assessment by individual buyers tends to be rough, say
1%, 2%, 5%, or 10% above the basic price, and rarely 1.26%, 2.95%, or 8.62%
above some basic price. In short, the observed average amenity premium
reflects the collective inclination of the market as a whole, not individual
buyers¡¦ inclination.
Notes:
The article and/or content contained herein are for general reference only
and are not meant to substitute for proper professional advice and/or due
diligence. The author(s) and Zeppelin, including its staff, associates,
consultants, executives and the like do not accept any responsibility or
liability for losses, damages, claims and the like arising out of the use or
reference to the content contained herein.
Back
to Home /
Back to Simple to Read Stuff Section
|